The fossil
fuel-based economy is unsustainable, both because the fossil fuels
themselves will eventually become scarce, and because burning fossil
fuels will change climate in large and unpredictable ways. Fossil
fuels are a “miracle” substance: they allow for a civilizational
structure of technologies, lifestyles and economic processes that
are very wasteful, and their disappearance will make such wasteful
structures impossible to maintain. In order to either prevent or
deal with the consequences of fossil fuel burnout, it will be
necessary to become much more efficient and will require a
restructuring to what I will call “the efficient economy”.
The waste-industrial-complex The first kind of human
waste is the employment of people and resources in sectors where
they are not needed. Unique to the U.S. are three sectors that stand
out for their profligacy:
the military, the health industry, and the prison
system.
Even not counting Iraq or expenses outside the Department of
Defense, next year’s military budget will be $550 billion, most of
which is unnecessary. By simply expanding Medicare to all
citizens, we could free up about 5% of the GDP that is now going to
medical insurance companies, whose main activity is to figure out
why they shouldn’t cover their members’ insurance
claims. “The
U.S. incarcerates the largest number of people in the world”,
according to Christopher Hartney at the National Council on Crime
and Dependency, in a fact sheet released in November of 2006.
According to Hartney, “The US has less than 5% of the world’s
population but over 23% of the world’s incarcerated people”. In a
2003 study, Marc Mauer of The Sentencing Project showed that nearly
a quarter of the nearly 2 million inmates now in prison were there
for drug offenses, up from only 40,000 in 1980. According to Mauer,
“Within the U.S., policy changes adopted under the rubric of the
‘get tough’ movement and the ‘war on drugs’ have contributed
substantially to the rising prison population”. [1]
According to the
website drugsense.com, in 2006, $50 billion was spent by Federal and
state governments on the war on drugs. An efficient society will not
have the “luxury” of engaging in wars and imprisonment of this
kind.
The dictatorship of the CEOs The
second, and for most of the world, most important source of waste is
the dictatorial way in which firms are organized. If the economy was
composed of firms in which all employees were owners and
decision-makers, we would be in a much better position to dispense
with fossil fuels.
Most firms are hierarchical, that is, there is one top manager,
often called the CEO, who is in effect a dictator. He -- usually a
he -- determines who will fill the ranks of managers underneath him,
which means that all of those managers are more focused on pleasing
the CEO than helping the firm. The CEO can reward himself with
whatever resources he wants, to the detriment of the firm (and
society).
The managers under the CEO all strive to increase their
departmental head count in an effort to show that they are more
important than their peers, in an attempt to convince the CEO that
they should be promoted before the others. Those managers, and the
CEO as well, hire as many people as they can to help them in their
internal struggle for power. The goal of the upwardly mobile manager
is to claim more power, and only secondarily to increase the firm’s
profits. Many of the people in these staffs serve police functions
over the people who actually produce the goods and services of the
firm. All of this behavior leads to larger and larger administrative
staffs. The late Seymour Melman called this “the expansion of
profits/power without limit”.
Administrative overkill Seymour Melman followed the
trends in the U.S. for administrative overhead for the better part
of a century. Looking just at manufacturing, he calculated that the
ratio of administrative workers to production workers in
manufacturing increased from 10:100 in 1899 to 53:100 in 1990. He
then calculated administrative overhead for the whole economy,
including entire industries, such as banking, as administrative
overhead. By 1990, the last year for which he as able to do the
calculations, 140 people were employed in the economy for every 100
people employed for production, while in 1947, the ration had been
42:100.[2]
The dynamics of a democratic firm are very different than the
dynamics of a dictatorial one, just as the dynamics of a democratic
polity are different than those of a dictatorship. In a firm which
is owned and controlled by all of its employees, the CEO is usually
elected indirectly by a directly elected governing council. While,
just as in a democracy, the head of state still has enormous power,
in a democratic firm, the CEO is constrained from rewarding himself
with the lavish lifestyle and staff that is business as usual for
your average CEO. The democratically-elected CEO must consider the
needs of his employees, and even the needs of the community in which
the employees live, if he is to retain the confidence of his
electorate.
When a hierarchy is top-down, information has a tendency not to
flow from the bottom up. Since the main goal of employees is to
satisfy the manager, not benefit the firm, information which
contradicts the opinions of the manager will not reach the manager.
Thus, the organization has difficulty adapting to new environments,
and loses much of its ability to improve its own operations and
innovate.
In a democratic firm, on the other hand, the employees are given
more responsibility; they are not required to stop and wait for a
manager to approve a new course of action; they feel freer to point
out problems and suggest new procedures. There is also evidence that
production lines are more stable when workers have more
decision-making power, leading to greater productivity.[3] The democratic firm
is more productive than the dictatorial one.
In an efficient society, it would be much more productive if all
firms were democratic, not dictatorial. Not only would the number of
employees necessary to produce goods and services be smaller, but
the quality of the goods and services would improve.
The world
according to Mondragon The clearest and most successful
example of democratic governance within the firm can be seen in the
Mondragon co-operative Corporation (MCC) in the Basque region
of Spain.[4] It is the 7th largest
industrial group in Spain, having been founded in 1956 by a Catholic
priest in order to make oil stoves and paraffin heaters. It employs
over 78,000 people in 264 co-operatives, and its industrial
group had sales of almost 12 billion euros in 2005; its financial
group, anchored by a bank, controlled about the same in assets
Why did this happen in the northeast corner of Spain? Spain has a
long tradition of syndicalism, the ownership of the firms by their
employees. However, there may be a special reason that the Basques
are able to pull this off, however. In his book “Against the Grain”,
Richard Manning argues that the Basque people of Spain can be linked
linguistically to the Cro-Magnon peoples of prehistoric Europe, who
drew the painting in the caves of Lascaux and dominated Europe until
the arrival of the grain people of the Caucasus and Middle East.[5] Throughout most of
history, agriculture has involved backbreaking labor and often,
according to the archaeological evidence, a hard life.
Agricultural
societies are where hierarchies first became established. Whether
this happened from necessity, imposition from outside, or both, one
can not know; but the result was that a grain surplus was created by
the unfortunate field workers which the elite used to keep
themselves and their military compatriots in fine fettle.
Effectively, the poor peasants were forced to create the food to
feed their masters. A priest class emerged to create religions to
try and convince the masses that servitude was what the gods wanted;
today, neoclassical economists serve essentially the same function.
So perhaps it is ironic that a priest helped to create the greatest
experiment in workplace democracy in modern history in the Basque
city of Mondragon. Basically, each member of the group of
co-operatives owns a share in his or her co-op, which the
member invests in with their own money or from money borrowed from
the Bank, and this share is not transferable to anybody else. If the
member leaves, they can take the accrued profits that have been
deposited in their account over the years, but they do not take
their share with them. This way, outside absentee owners can not
take over the co-ops. The members elect the governing council for
their co-op; there are 650 members of the Co-operative Congress that
are delegated by the individual members, and there is also the
General Assembly of all members who collectively elect the Governing
Council of the MCC, which picks the top managers.
The bank, known as the Working People’s Bank, helps new
co-ops to become established, or helps to maintain or expand the
existing businesses. The Bank therefore serves as a central unifying
force in the group, much like the banks within the Japanese
keiretsu, helping with technical advice as well as financial
aid.
The system of co-ops expanded from about 25,000 workers in 1992
to its present 78,000. 81% of the employees within the Basque region
are members of the co-ops, but because they expanded so rapidly,
almost half of their employees who are not in the Basque region are
not members. The MCC believes that potential members in nonBasque
regions have to build up an understanding of the co-op culture
before they let them become permanent members. Since training is a
huge part of the Mondragon system (there are 4,000 students at their
own university), they are starting to train nonBasques in a
“participative enterprise” model, as they put it.
You can contact Jon Rynn directly on his jonrynn.blogspot.com .
You can also find old blog entries and longer articles at
economicreconstruction.com. Please feel free to reach him at
This email address is being protected from spam bots, you need
Javascript enabled to view it
.
[1]
“Comparable International
Rates of Incarceration: An examination of causes and trends”,
presented to the U.S. Commission on Civil Rights, Marc Mauer, The
Sentencing Project, 2006 [2]
See Seymour Melman,
“After Capitalism”, 2001, A.A. Knopf, p.176-83. David M. Gordon also
discussed this problem in his book, “Fat and Mean: The corporate
squeeze of working Americans and the myth of managerial
‘Downsizing’”. Gordon asserts that managerial waste is worse than
military waste. [3]
“After
Capitalism”, p.424-26. [4]
The data for the
following discussion of Mondragon comes from their website.
See also a discussion in “After Capitalism”, 2001, Seymour Melman,
pages 351-8. The classic book is “Making Mondragon” by William
Whyte, 1991, Institute For Labor Studies Press [5]
See also http://folk.uio.no/paltr/basque_mystery.html
for a scholarly and sympathetic look at the claim of Cromagnon
ancestors, and the book “The Basque History of the World”, Mark
Kurlansky, 2001, Vintage Canada, although this scholarly article disputes
the assertion. At the very least, the Basque were there before the
agricultural peoples were. |